WHITEPAPER

December 13, 2013

A call for honest fools

By Dylan Grice Global Strategist for Société Générale [email protected]

With public anger at the finance industry growing by the day, “banker greed” and the “bonus culture” are widely blamed for all that is wrong in today’s world. From public sector cuts to the neglect of manufacturing to widening disparity between haves and have-nots, disillusionment with the banking industry remains a common and constant theme. Th e fi nancial problems of today are indeed complex, yet such anger is directed entirely at symptoms rather than underlying causes. A sound analysis of the integrity of any construction must surely begin with that construct’s foundations, and the foundations of our capital markets are our central banks. Th is paper questions the knowledge base upon which central banks act to eff ectively manipulate capital markets in the name of the common good. It argues that faulty reasoning and presumed knowledge lie at the very core of our capital markets behaviour, and therefore at the very core of today’s crises

It seems counterintuitive, but “trying harder” doesn’t always work. A famous experiment asked groups of people for and against capital punishment to evaluate two separate studies, one for capital punishment and the other against. Th e group in favour of capital punishment found the study in favour to be more valid, while the group against capital punishment found the study against to be more valid, and that after reading each report, each group’s prior beliefs were strengthened as was their hostility to the other. What I found especially fascinating was that when the study was rerun only this time the experimenters explicitly told the subjects to be “strictly unbiased in their judgement” (i.e. “try harder”) the eff ect was to make the polarisation even more pronounced!

It is this aspect to those studies I want to think about here, the incorrect application of faulty models. In essence, that is all that study was really about. Subjects applied a faulty model – a mental algorithm saying “accept only supporting evidence” – which resulted in a biased assessment of the evidence. “Trying harder” did not work because the problem was the faulty model, not the lack of eff ort and applying that faulty model with more determination just caused an even bigger error. Psychologists have a name for this. Th ey call it the “lost pilot eff ect” after the lost pilot trying to reassure his passengers by saying, “I have no idea where we’re going, but we are making good time!”

Flawed thinking got us into this mess, but rather than changing that fl awed thinking, our policy makers are applying it with even more rigour. We have more debt for insolvent borrowers, more fi nancial engineering, more complicated banking regulations, more blaming speculators for everything, more monetary experimentation by central banks. Our policy makers have absolutely no idea what they’re doing, but they’re giving it a go!

The latest from the Fed provides a wonderful example. Undeterred by the latest calamitous failure of Consumer Price Index (CPI) targeting regimes (a brief history of which will be presented below) it has announced an explicit 2% inflation target. But why? Would an explicit target have made any difference to the last crisis? Will it prevent the next one? And where did this 2% come from? We don’t know, but we suspect that past uninformed capital market tinkering has failed to control the uncontrollable, and we are pretty sure these ones will too.

In fact, if such tinkering has in the past been the primary cause of crises, then why won’t this latest attempt – the 2% inflation target – be the cause of the next one? There are certainly precedents. Targeting stable “prices” isn’t a new idea. The first experiment was actually conducted in the US in the 1920s, and apparently it was successful. Indeed, so stable were consumer prices then that the authorities assumed there was no inflationary threat. Moreover, so enamoured were they with this brilliant new idea that stable consumer prices were both a necessary and sufficient condition for economic stability, that the NY Fed adopted it as a policy objective. On January 11th 1925, then-Governor Benjamin Strong wrote to a friend:

“That it was my belief, and I thought it was shared by all others in the Federal Reserve System, that our whole policy in the future, as in the past, would be directed towards the stability of prices so far as it was possible for us to influence prices.”

During the 1927 Stabilization hearings before the Committee on Banking and Currency regarding a Bill to amend the Federal Reserve Act to provide for the “stabilization of the price level for commodities in general”, the governor was asked if the Fed could stabilize prices more than it had done in the past. Strong replied:

“I personally think that the administration of the Federal Reserve System since the reaction of 1921 has been just as nearly directed as reasonable human wisdom could direct it toward that very object”

 

Download the full whitepaper (pdf , 1.12 MB)
Download

RELATED THOUGHT PIECES

August 10, 2021
The Climate is Ripe for Change
We propose a green bond through a Public-Private partnership to tackle climate change can give pension schemes reliable cash flows to meet liabilities while also making fundamental changes to the best practice model for the investment of long-term pools of capital.
February 17, 2021
The Role of the Investment Management Industry and a Prescription for the Future
During this crisis, we have all been made acutely aware of the fact that companies should not just be primarily profit generating machines but purposeful providers of solutions to the needs and wants of real people. The consequence of fulfilling those purposes are long term sustainable returns to investors.
February 14, 2020
Open Letter to Larry Fink - Welcome BlackRock
Economics has developed as a science, conveniently forgetting its roots in political philosophy. Unfortunately that ‘science’ is severely dated, and the functioning of the global capital markets has become separated from the real world. A simple thought experiment throws light on the theoretically correct strategies for a rational saver, but leaves us with unsatisfactory answers. Neglecting the societal context of our saving activity only serves to further isolate the capital markets. Instead, a self-perpetuating system requires investors to evolve from simple allocators of capital to its steward, with far broader responsibilities. Maximising holistic returns represents practical action of the responsibility by investors, and stretches far beyond creating wealth simply for its own sake.